Sympathy and similarity: the evolutionary dynamics of cooperation.
نویسنده
چکیده
T he advantage of mutual help is threatened by defectors, who exploit the benefits provided by others without providing benefits in return. Cooperation can only be sustained if it is preferentially channeled toward cooperators and away from defectors. But how? A deceptively simple idea is to distinguish cooperators from defectors by tagging them. It clearly is in the interest of cooperators to use some distinctive cue to assort with their like. Such an assortment, however, conflicts with the interests of the cheaters, who have every incentive to also acquire that tag. This makes for an inherently unstable situation. The history of evolutionary thinking on this issue is long. An article in this issue of PNAS by Antal et al. (1) opens new ground by providing an in-depth analysis of a selectionmutation model. The first to investigate a tag for altruism was W. D. Hamilton (2). He conceived what he called a supergene, able to produce (i) a distinctive phenotypic trait, (ii) the faculty to recognize the trait in others, and (iii) the propensity to direct benefits toward bearers of that trait, even though this entails a fitness cost. Soon afterward, Richard Dawkins described Hamilton’s thought experiment by using as phenotypic trait the fanciful example of a green beard. The supergene was now termed ‘‘green beard gene,’’ in part to acknowledge its inherent unlikelihood. ‘‘Too good to be true,’’ were Dawkins’ words (3): for the gene would have to be able to program for 3 effects, namely the feature, its recognition, and the altruistic propensity. The green-beard concept relates to both major approaches to cooperation in evolutionary biology, namely kin selection (2) and reciprocal altruism (4). It helps in promoting assortment between cooperators; as a result, cooperators can get more than they give, so that altruism becomes a thriving business. Because wearers of green beards both confer and receive benefits, the tag works as a kind of promise that the altruistic action will be returned, not necessarily by the recipient, but by another member of the green-bearded guild. In this sense, the green beard mediates an indirect form of reciprocation, through third parties. In the usual models of indirect reciprocity, ‘‘good guys’’ are recognized by their reputation, which is based on their past deeds (5). Here, however, recognition is ensured by a phenotypic trait, which is a less sophisticated (and possibly less reliable) signal. Mostly, the green beard is studied in the context of kin selection. If you carry a green beard, your relatives are likely to carry one, too. Directing benefits at green-bearded individuals confers the benefits preferentially to your kin and raises your indirect fitness (because your kin shares your genes with a higherthan-average probability). In many cases, kin are living close by. But the viscosity of the population (to use another term by Hamilton) is not enough to guarantee a local increase in cooperation, because it is counterbalanced by a local increase in competition. Limited dispersal alone is therefore not enough. A gene for kin recognition can help to direct positive rather than negative effects toward relatives. But it is important to realize that the green beard can promote altruism beyond the realm of the family. Some 10 years ago, it was found that green beards are not as implausible as their name suggests. In particular, Haig (6) remarked that genes for homophilic cell adhesion could perform all 3 tasks required from a green-beard gene (trait, recognition, and action) by coding for a surface protein that allows them to stick to copies of themselves on other cells. A few years later, it was found that csA genes in Dictyostelium discoideum fit the bill (7). In hard times, these amoeba literally stick together to form stalks for dispersing their spores. A similar gene has also been discovered in flocculating yeast cells (8). Other candidates for more sophisticated green-beard effects have been found in ants and lizards. An obvious way to cheat is to grow a green beard but skip the altruism. For homophilic cell adhesion, this seems barely feasible. In other examples, cheating may be prevented by genetic constraints. But in principle, one would expect that a tight link between a gene for altruistic behavior and a gene for tag recognition will ultimately be broken, and cooperation be destroyed. Surprisingly, it turned out that if the link is not too tight (but not too loose either), a dynamic regime of cooperation can emerge, based on tag diversity. Whenever some tag becomes too frequent, it can be faked by defectors, but cooperative behavior subsists nevertheless, by allying itself with another tag. This phenomenon has been termed ‘‘beard chromodynamics,’’ to suggest that green beards can over time be replaced by red,
منابع مشابه
The Lobbying, Bribery, and Compliance: An Evolutionary Model of Social Factors
Abstract Connecting to rule-makers in order to set favorable rules (lobbying) or paying government executives to bend the current rule (bribing) are the two main strategies for influencing government. This study in an evolutionary game model explain why bribing may become widespread while other states like compliance and cooperative lobbying are Pareto superior. The theoretical model is used ...
متن کاملSympathy with Adam Smith and reflexions on self
AdamSmith’s account of themoral sentiments resonateswithmodern themes in evolutionary biology. His distinction between our reasons and the reasons for these reasons recalls the evolutionary biologist’s emphasis on different levels of causal explanation. In this view, the proximate goals of our psychologicalmotivations are different in kind from the ultimate reasons why we have evolved these mot...
متن کاملA MODEL FOR EVOLUTIONARY DYNAMICS OF WORDS IN A LANGUAGE
Human language, over its evolutionary history, has emerged as one of the fundamental defining characteristic of the modern man. However, this milestone evolutionary process through natural selection has not left any ’linguistic fossils’ that may enable us to trace back the actual course of development of language and its establishment in human societies. Lacking analytical tools to fathom the cr...
متن کاملA new approach on studying the stability of evolutionary game dynamics for financial systems
Financial market modeling and prediction is a difficult problem and drastic changes of the price causes nonlinear dynamic that makes the price prediction one of the most challenging tasks for economists. Since markets always have been interesting for traders, many traders with various beliefs are highly active in a market. The competition among two agents of traders, namely trend follo...
متن کاملروشهای مدلسازی تطوری در اقتصاد (با تاکید بر عناصر مشترک سازنده آنها)
In this paper we have tried mention to some sort of thewell-known evolutionary modeling approaches in economic territory such as Multi Agent simulations, Evolutionary Computation and Evolutionary Game Theory. As it has been mentioned in the paper, in recent years, the number of Evolutionary contributions applied to Multi-Agent models increased remarkably. However until now there is no consensus...
متن کاملSelf-similar fractals and arithmetic dynamics
The concept of self-similarity on subsets of algebraic varieties is defined by considering algebraic endomorphisms of the variety as `similarity' maps. Self-similar fractals are subsets of algebraic varieties which can be written as a finite and disjoint union of `similar' copies. Fractals provide a framework in which, one can unite some results and conjectures in Diophantine g...
متن کاملذخیره در منابع من
با ذخیره ی این منبع در منابع من، دسترسی به آن را برای استفاده های بعدی آسان تر کنید
برای دانلود متن کامل این مقاله و بیش از 32 میلیون مقاله دیگر ابتدا ثبت نام کنید
ثبت ناماگر عضو سایت هستید لطفا وارد حساب کاربری خود شوید
ورودعنوان ژورنال:
- Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America
دوره 106 21 شماره
صفحات -
تاریخ انتشار 2009